Commentary

Rebutting "Goa's 'Taxi Mafia': What Tourists Need To Know"

  • Goa’s taxi cartel isn’t misunderstood — it’s a state-protected monopoly that thrives on fear.

Ajay MallareddyJun 17, 2025, 11:59 AM | Updated Jun 21, 2025, 03:38 PM IST
A taxi stand in Margao in South Goa. (Joegoauk Goa via Flickr)

A taxi stand in Margao in South Goa. (Joegoauk Goa via Flickr)


A recent article in Scroll.in titled "Goa's taxi mafia: What tourists need to know" attempts to depict Goa's taxi industry as a misunderstood group maintaining a traditional, community-based model. However, this portrayal fundamentally misrepresents reality and misleads readers.

The author romanticizes what operates as a cartel, a "taxi mafia" that holds tourists and locals hostage through coercion, intimidation, and inflated prices.

The article states that drivers oppose "a business that they have built and sustained over years being handed over to large corporations." This treats the entire transportation market as property belonging to current taxi operators.

Taxi drivers aren't market-owners but participants in a transportation market that serves both drivers and customers alike. The current taxi system thrives solely because the state protects their monopoly privileges, creating poor service, inflated prices, and limited economic opportunities for consumers and honest drivers alike.

The Reality Behind Goa's "Cooperative" Taxi System

The article claims there is "an unwritten rule that after they drop off a passenger, they will not pick another ride as they return to their point of origin... This reflects the cooperative nature of a business in which even one taxi operator's greed for rides outside his territory could break a chain of trust."

Nothing about this system is cooperative. Taxi unions enforce it through violence and intimidation. The author's euphemistic language conceals how drivers who serve customers outside designated zones face harassment, physical threats, and vehicle damage.

This isn't voluntary cooperation but a cartel maintained through fear. The 50 per cent return fare surcharge is a monopoly tax on consumers with no alternatives. Territorial restrictions severely limit mobility and damage tourism.

How does territorial exclusivity benefit the community when taxi unions violently prevent a Candolim driver from picking up passengers in Benaulim? These monopolies serve vested interests, not communities.

What The Guidelines Actually Proposed

The article misrepresents what the draft guidelines actually proposed, creating a false narrative about driver exploitation.

The draft guidelines heavily favoured existing taxi drivers, offering guaranteed government fares, Rs 10 lakh health insurance, vehicle insurance reimbursement, protections for female drivers, and participation restricted to Goan permit holders only.

The transport department stated these guidelines addressed "poor service, high fares and failure to adhere to regulated meters" following tourist complaints. This directly contradicts the author's portrayal of a well-functioning system.

Current drivers routinely ignore government rates and quote arbitrary prices based on customer assessment. The guidelines would have created transparency while maintaining high rates plus aggregator commission.

The Scroll article attempts to justify high fares with a bizarre comparison: "45 minutes in Goa costs ₹1,200 vs 45 minutes in Mumbai costs ₹500."

This framing is disingenuous - everyone knows taxi fares are distance-based, not time-based. Moreover, the ₹1,200 rate for 30km that the author cites drastically understates actual pricing. Tourists report wildly fluctuating charges: ₹1,500 for 20km (₹75/km) and ₹600 for just 2.5km (₹240/km). These wildly inconsistent rates expose the complete absence of any pricing logic. The author's attempt at mathematical justification is meaningless when drivers simply charge whatever they think they can extract.

Different vehicle categories having different rates is standard practice worldwide - Uber Sedan versus Uber XL have different pricing. More importantly, the author admits that "the lack of standardised fares is a failure of enforcement," inadvertently acknowledging that drivers routinely ignore official rates. This supports rather than refutes criticism of the current system.

The author criticizes app surge-pricing while ignoring that Goan drivers practice constant informal surge-pricing regardless of conditions. Apps provide transparent, algorithmic pricing; the current system offers arbitrary, hidden pricing with no consistency.

Surge-pricing efficiently increases supply during high demand. When prices rise, more drivers choose to work, creating more available rides. This benefits both customers (more options) and drivers (higher earnings). The current system's arbitrary inflation serves no market function beyond enriching monopoly operators.

The author warns that app aggregators use "predatory techniques" to "establish a monopoly" that "coerces local cab drivers to sign up" or "forces them out of business." This is pure projection. The author defends actual predatory techniques (violence, territorial restrictions) that maintain an actual monopoly (state-backed taxi cartel) involving actual coercion (physical threats) while characterizing voluntary interactions with aggregators as "coercion."

The irony is staggering: drivers can choose whether to work with apps, but face violence for serving customers in "wrong" territories. The author calls voluntary choice "coercion" while defending a system built on literal coercion.

The author defends a system the government admits is broken while mischaracterizing reforms that would have protected drivers. He simultaneously claims this is a successful cooperative model while admitting that drivers getting "even one trip a day is considered lucky."

This contradiction exposes the system's fundamental failure - it doesn't even work well for the drivers the author claims to champion.

The Real Story About App Failure and Community Claims

The author claims existing apps "have failed because demand in Goa is not as intense as it is in large cities, and is unevenly distributed. The algorithms of the apps cannot adapt to Goa's humane ways of doing business."

These apps didn't fail due to "algorithms not adapting" or insufficient demand. They failed because taxi union members systematically attack cab drivers who use these platforms and restrict them from making pickups in many areas, preventing effective operation.

Tourists consistently complain about lack of transportation options. The deterrent isn't algorithmic limitations but credible threats from taxi unions against competitive drivers.

The author romanticizes territorial restrictions as "community cooperation" while ignoring they prevent supply from meeting obvious demand. The "taxi mafia" violently suppresses attempts to serve that demand.

The article justifies the cartel by citing marginalised community membership. However, a study of Uber drivers found that "individuals from marginalized groups and religious minorities use the platform to participate in an occupation that eschews social discrimination in their work life." Aggregator platforms actually empower marginalised communities through inclusive employment free from traditional job discrimination.

The article's invocation of Bahujan identity exemplifies a common tactic in Indian policy debates: deflecting criticism of broken systems by invoking identity markers. This weaponizes social justice language to shield monopolistic practices from scrutiny, making economic criticism appear as social oppression.

Real empowerment would come from open competition that allows any qualified driver to enter the market based on merit, not social connections or union approval. This creates opportunities for marginalised individuals currently excluded from the taxi trade while rewarding all drivers based on service quality rather than territorial control.

Old taxi rates at the Dabolim airport in Goa, dating back to circa 2006 (Wikimedia Commons)

The current system operates as a state-backed monopoly serving narrow interests rather than community empowerment. Goa's taxi drivers defend monopoly privileges that restrict opportunities for other community members.

Conclusion

The original article romanticises Goa's taxi situation by framing monopolistic practices as "cooperative community business" and territorial restrictions as "trust building," obscuring the real impact on tourists, businesses, and economic development.

A cursory glance at any major travel forum reveals a consistent pattern: tourists call Goa amazing but warn others about taxi extortion, with many vowing not to return because of it. News reports document how the "taxi mafia" and rising costs are driving tourists away, directly affecting local businesses.

These are just two examples of countless such incidents that happen routinely, creating systematic harassment precisely when Goa seeks to attract more visitors. This is the real consequence of the system the article defends.

The evidence shows the article defends not entrepreneurial success or community empowerment, but a state-protected cartel that restricts competition, inflates prices, and damages Goa's reputation.

Why protect a system that fails drivers and tourists alike just to preserve monopoly privileges for an entrenched few?

Join our WhatsApp channel - no spam, only sharp analysis