Ideas
R Jagannathan
Sep 09, 2016, 10:58 AM | Updated 10:58 AM IST
Save & read from anywhere!
Bookmark stories for easy access on any device or the Swarajya app.
Railway Minister Suresh Prabhu has been widely criticised for “experimenting” with “surge pricing” in a limited way on Rajdhani, Shatabdi and Duronto fares. The criticism is largely based on two ideas: that the Railways are a monopoly, and so attempts to squeeze higher fares are an abuse of its monopoly; and that the formula for implementing dynamic pricing based on demand is wrong. It seems, fares can be jacked up by up to 50 percent even if 40 percent of seats are empty (read two editorial comments here and here).
Both criticisms are valid – but only up to
a point. To criticise a formula for dynamic fares even before it is fully
implemented and the results verifiable is wrong. If surge pricing starts coming
into effect when too many seats are vacant, the net result will be a regular
loss of passengers to other modes of transport. So, presumably, the surge
formula will be corrected at some point based on experience. One presumes
Prabhu is not trying to de-optimise rail revenues.
The other argument – that this is an
abuse of monopoly – is theoretically valid, but in a situation where the
political consensus to open up the railways for private competition does not
exist, it is essentially an argument for status quo, barring probably the appointment
of a regulator to decide fares.
The problem with monopoly is that we
tend to see it too narrowly. Railway travel may be a monopoly of the Indian
Railways, but travel in general is not. If we take passenger travel as the market
being addressed, competitive alternatives to railway travel exist. Air fares
are fairly competitive on busy routes compared to railway upper class travel,
especially First Class in Rajdhani; bus fares too are competitive on shorter
point-to-point routes. And then there are luxury taxi services between
short-distance cities.
The point is we should not define
monopoly is such a limited way in a world where options are expanding.
Monopolists ultimately lose by making costs so expensive that other substitutes
emerge.
The abuse of railway monopoly in
freight has ensured a large shift in cargoes to road transport. The abuse of
government monopoly in power and coal has made solar power now nearly as
competitive.
So the real issue is the wisdom of
experimenting with surge pricing in the one area where passengers have many
options between rail, air and road transport. But then it is politically
impossible to introduce surge pricing where it is really needed – in lower
class travel in the railways.
Moreover, monopolies are contextual.
Outside a cinema hall, the limited number of autorickshaws available compared
to the surge in passenger demand makes autos a temporary monopoly. This is why
surge pricing helps, since it either improves supply or reduces demand. The
railways are no exception to this rule. If surge pricing works, it would enable
even a monopoly to offer more trains on busy routes.
At the core of all our objections to
surge pricing – whether in the railways or in air fares or in taxi hailing
services – is our innate distrust of the markets as an efficient allocator of
resources. Politicians and the public believe that someone should have the
power to determine what travel or food or education or land should cost, and
not the markets.
But it is this distrust of the
markets that ultimately creates inefficiency and higher costs.
And this is why even appointing regulators
to determine rail fares will not solve the problem. What do regulators do? They
will look at the cost of running a service and recommend a price that is
presumably fair to producer and consumer. In perennially loss-making services
like second class travel, any future regulator’s recommended increase may be
less than needed, but they will essentially try to narrow the cost-breakeven
gap.
What they cannot do is regulate
the cost of providing a service. How valid is our belief in regulators’ ability
to solve a problem when that problem is a structural one - overmanning, poor
use of technology and lack of accountability in the public sector. The issue is
to change the cost base, and a railway regulator cannot do that without the
government first allowing competition and corporatisation of the railways.
And we aren’t even talking of the
real monopoly that distorts costs: the railway unions, who will not allow a
reduction in the workforce or link wages to productivity.
We have regulators in the power sector, but has that resulted in lower power tariffs anywhere? On the contrary, state governments artificially keep power costs for the rural sector low, and allow state discoms to accumulate huge amounts of overdues, which ultimately have to be paid for from higher tariffs and taxes.
So, having a regulator in a
system where prices are not set by the markets is, by definition, a
non-solution. In any case, assuming a railways regulator asks the ministry to
up second class fares, will any politician dare to take that medicine in full?
The only solution is for politicians
to accept the reality that markets are more efficient allocators of resources,
and regulators are useful to ensure that competition is fair to all players.
But we are nowhere near that stage, and are, in fact, moving further away from
markets in many areas.
To criticise Prabhu using theoretical
arguments about monopoly and unfair pricing makes no sense till we can agree to
allow him to throw open the railways to competition. He is, like all ministers
before him, trying to cross-subsidise populist underpricing of second class
travel by fleecing the rich.
Jagannathan is Editorial Director, Swarajya. He tweets at @TheJaggi.